Friedrich List y la economía política nacional

dc.contributor.advisorAlmario Garcia, Oscar
dc.contributor.authorMaya Muñoz, Guillermo Antonio
dc.contributor.cvlacMaya Muñoz, Guillermospa
dc.contributor.googlescholarMay Muñoz, Guillermo Antonio [57xa-NcAAAAJ&hl=es]spa
dc.contributor.orcidMaya Muñoz, Guillermo Antonio [000-0002-9571-297X]spa
dc.contributor.orcidAlmario Garcia, Oscar [0000-0003-4312-3206]spa
dc.contributor.researchgateMaya-Muñoz, Guillermospa
dc.date.accessioned2023-11-03T14:48:14Z
dc.date.available2023-11-03T14:48:14Z
dc.date.issued2023-11-02
dc.description.abstractEsta tesis tiene como objetivo presentar y analizar el pensamiento de F. List, pasando por sus orígenes renacentistas mercantilistas, su configuración a partir de su exilio en EE. UU. en 1825, hasta su obra de madurez, El Sistema Nacional de Economía Política (1841). Igualmente, exploro sus influencias tanto en EE. UU. como en Alemania, pasando por Japón, China, Corea del Sur y Latinoamérica, que se convirtieron en países con un gran desarrollo económico, exceptuando a esta última, bajo un proceso de industrialización orientado por un estado desarrollista. En los primeros dos capítulos abordo el análisis de las obras de List, Petition (1819), Outlines (1827), Natural System (1837) y National System (1841), y Land System (1842); en el capítulo 3, las etapas económicas; en el capítulo 4, las influencias de List, tanto sobre sus críticos, Marx, por ejemplo, como sobre el pensamiento de economistas modernos. En este sentido se puede trazar una línea genética intelectual entre la obra de List, la escuela histórica alemana, y la escuela institucionalista germano-americana. En el último capítulo 5 estudio los aportes de Prebisch que sustenta el modelo de sustitución de importaciones de la CEPAL, sus logros y fracasos. Sin embargo, el Consenso de Washington ha desindustrializado y reprimarizado las economías Latinoamericanas, en mayor o en menor grado en comparación de unas y otras, con actividades extractivas, y ha agudizado la concentración del ingreso y los indicadores sociales. El objetivo de este proceso histórico-analítico es destacar que el pensamiento listiano sigue siendo vigente para repensar e impulsar las políticas de desarrollo y trasformación estructural de los países de menor desarrollo, y que para hacerlo es necesario un estado con mayores y mejores capacidades, como agencia colectiva y organizada de la nación, para que sea más poderoso en la dirección de la economía. Es ineludible. (Texto tomado de la fuente)spa
dc.description.abstractThis thesis aims to present and analyze the thought of F. List, going through its mercantilist Renaissance origins, its configuration from his exile in the US in 1825, to his mature work, The National System of Political Economy (1841). Likewise, I explore its influences both in the US and in Germany, passing through Japan, China, South Korea and Latin America, which became countries with great economic development, except for the latter, under an industrialization process oriented by a developmentalist state. In the first two chapters I address the analysis of the works of List, Petition (1819), Outlines (1827), Natural System (1837) and National System (1841), and Land System (1842); in chapter 3, the economic stages; in chapter 4, List's influences, both on his critics, Marx, for example, and on the thought of modern economists. In this sense, an intellectual genetic line can be drawn between the work of List, the German historical school, and the German American institutionalist school. In the last chapter 5, I study the contributions of Prebisch that supports the import substitution model of ECLAC, its achievements and failures. However, the Washington Consensus has deindustrialized and reprimarized the Latin American economies, to a greater or lesser degree compared to one another, with extractive activities, and has sharpened the concentration of income and social indicators. The objective of this analytical-historical process is to highlight that listian thought is still valid to rethink and promote development policies and structural transformation of less developed countries, and that to do so, a state with greater and better capacities is necessary, as a collective and organized agency of the nation, to make it more powerful in the direction of the economy. It is inescapable. Keywords: nationalism, manufacturieng
dc.description.curricularareaÁrea Curricular de Ciencias Humanas y Socialesspa
dc.description.degreelevelDoctoradospa
dc.description.degreenameDoctor en Ciencias Humanas y Socialesspa
dc.format.extent413 páginasspa
dc.format.mimetypeapplication/pdfspa
dc.identifier.instnameUniversidad Nacional de Colombiaspa
dc.identifier.reponameRepositorio Institucional Universidad Nacional de Colombiaspa
dc.identifier.repourlhttps://repositorio.unal.edu.co/spa
dc.identifier.urihttps://repositorio.unal.edu.co/handle/unal/84877
dc.language.isospaspa
dc.publisherUniversidad Nacional de Colombiaspa
dc.publisher.branchUniversidad Nacional de Colombia - Sede Medellínspa
dc.publisher.facultyFacultad de Ciencias Humanas y Económicasspa
dc.publisher.programMedellín - Ciencias Humanas y Económicas - Doctorado en Ciencias Humanas y Socialesspa
dc.relation.indexedRedColspa
dc.relation.indexedLaReferenciaspa
dc.relation.referencesAstorga, Pablo, Ame R. Bergés, and Valpy Fitzgerald (2004) “The Standard of Living in Latin America During the Twentieth Century”, Latin American Centre St Antony’s College, Oxford University, No 54, March, pp. 35.spa
dc.relation.referencesBaer, W. (1984). Industrialization in Latin America: Successes and Failures. The Journal of Economic Education, 15(2), 124-135. doi:10.2307/1182052.spa
dc.relation.referencesBallinger, C. (2011) Mercantilism and the Rise of the West: Towards a Geography of Mercantilism. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2164912spa
dc.relation.referencesBell, J. (1942). Frederick List, Champion of Industrial Capitalism. The Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography, 66(1), 56-83. www.jstor.org/stable/20087445spa
dc.relation.referencesBlaug, M. (1984). Review: “Friedrich List, Economist and Visionary 1789-1846 by W. O. Henderson; and Friedrich List, the Natural System of Political Economy 1837 by W. O. Henderson, Economica, 51(203), 368–369. doi: 10.2307/2554561.spa
dc.relation.referencesBoianovsky, M. (2015). Between Lévi-Strauss and Braudel: Furtado and the historical-structural method in Latin American political economy, Journal of Economic Methodology Vol. 22 (4), pp. 1-26.spa
dc.relation.referencesBruzzi, Luiz. (2015a). From “social economy” to “national political economy”: German economic ideas in Brazil, XI Congressso Brasileiro de História Econômica, 14-16 de setembro, pp. 25.spa
dc.relation.referencesCaton, H. (1985). The Preindustrial Economics of Adam Smith. The Journal of Economic History, 45(4), 833-853. www.jstor.org/stable/2121882spa
dc.relation.referencesChang, H-J. (1999). The Economic Theory of the Developmental State. In M. Woo-Cumings (Ed.), The Developmental State (pp. 182–199). Cornell University Press. http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.7591/j.ctvv411jz.10spa
dc.relation.referencesChang, H-J, & Lin, J. (2009) “Should Industrial Policy in Developing Countries Conform to Comparative Advantage or Defy it? A Debate Between Justin Lin and Ha-Joon Chang”, Development Policy Review, Vol. 27 (5).spa
dc.relation.referencesDaastøl, A. (2013). A Review of Contributions of Friedrich List Commemorating his 225-Year Anniversary. The Pakistan Development Review, 52(2), 169–174. http://www.jstor.org/stable/24397934spa
dc.relation.referencesGeloso, V. and Salter, A. (2020) State capacity and economic development: Causal mechanism or correlative filter?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Volume 170, Pages 372-385, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2019.12.015spa
dc.relation.referencesHudson, M. (2021). Super Imperialism. The Economic Strategy of American Empire. IsletVerlag. (Original publicado en 1972).spa
dc.relation.referencesHughes, M. (1992). Review of Communism and Nationalism: Karl Marx versus Friedrich List by Roman Szporluk. The English Historical Review, 107(424), 740-741. www.jstor.org/stable/575316spa
dc.relation.referencesHurtado, J. (2014, marzo 19). Paul Krugman en Lima: "Los acuerdos comerciales están sobredimensionados", Semana Económica. Ince, O. (2016). “Development” in Fundamental Concepts in International Law: The Construction of a Discipline. Ed. Jean d’Aspremont & Sahib Singh.spa
dc.relation.referencesJameson, K. (1986). Latin American structuralism: A methodological perspective. World Development, 14(2), 223-232.spa
dc.relation.referencesKunst, David. 2019, Premature Deindustrialization through The Lens of Occupations: Which Jobs, Why, and Where? Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper TI 2019-033/V, August, pp. 42.spa
dc.relation.referencesKuttner, R. (1991) The End of Laissez-Faire: National Purpose and the Global Economy After the Cold War, Alfred Knopf, Inc, NY, pp. 304.spa
dc.relation.referencesLadenthin, E. (1912). Zur Entwicklung der nationalökonomischen Ansichten F. Lists von 1820- 1825. Wien, Konegenspa
dc.relation.referencesLenz, F. (1930). Friedrich List, "die Vulgärökonomie" und Karl Marx List, Friedrich (1827). Outlines of American Political Economy. Editorial Michael Liebig. (Original publicado en 1997).spa
dc.relation.referencesLove, J. (1990). Theorizing Underdevelopment: Latin America and Romania 1860-1950, Estudios Avançados, 4 (8), São Paulo Jan/Apr pp. 62.95.spa
dc.relation.referencesLove, J. 2005. The Rise and Decline of Economic Structuralism in Latin America, Latin American Research Review, Vol. 40, No. 3, October, pp. 100-125.spa
dc.relation.referencesMagnusson, L. (2009). Nation, State and the Industrial Revolution: The Visible Hand. Routledge.spa
dc.relation.referencesMadgavkar, A., Bill Schaninger, Sven Smit, Jonathan Woetzel, Hamid Samandari, Davis Carlin, Jeongmin Seong, and Kanmani Chockalingam (2022). Human capital at work: The value of experience. McKinsey.spa
dc.relation.referencesMarshall, A. (1920). Principles of Economics. Macmillan; The Online Library of Liberty A Project Of Liberty Fund, Inc. (Original publicado en 1890).spa
dc.relation.referencesMunn, T. (1954). La riqueza de Inglaterra por el comercio exterior. FCE. (Original publicado en 1664).spa
dc.relation.referencesMyint, H. (1977). Adam Smith’s Theory of International Trade in the Perspective of Economic Development. Economica, 44(175), 231–248. https://doi.org/10.2307/2553648spa
dc.relation.referencesNYTimes (2022, aug 3). Congress Is Giving Billions to the Chip Industry. Strings Are Attached. https://www.nytimes.com/2022/08/03/business/economy/chip-industry-congress.htmlspa
dc.relation.referencesNelson, R., & Pack, H. (1999). The Asian Miracle and Modern Growth Theory. The Economic Journal, 109(457), 416-436. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/2565712spa
dc.relation.referencesNicholson, J. (1909). Introduction to Friedrich List, the National System of Political Economy. Longmans, Green And Co.spa
dc.relation.referencesNunn, N. (2014). 7. Historical Development. En Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (Eds.). Handbook of Economic Growth (pp. 347-401).spa
dc.relation.referencesO'Brien, P. (1989). The Impact of the Revolutionary and Napoleonic Wars, 1793-1815, on the Long-Run Growth of the British Economy. Review (Fernand Braudel Center), 12(3), 335- 395. Retrieved June 4, 2020, from www.jstor.org/stable/40241130spa
dc.relation.referencesO' Brien, P. (1997a). The Britishness of the first industrial revolution and the British contribution to the industrialization of ‘follower countries’ on the mainland, 1756–1914. Diplomacy & Statecraft, 8(3), 48-67, DOI: 10.1080/09592299708406055spa
dc.relation.referencesOcampo, J. (2008). Hirschman, la industrialización y la teoría del desarrollo, Revista Desarrollo y Sociedad, núm. 62, Universidad de los Andes, Colombia, julio-diciembre, pp. 41-65spa
dc.relation.referencesÖzçelik, E. y Özveren, E. (2016). Friedrich List & Joseph Schumpeter: Strange bedfellows in the pedigree of (development) economics? METU Studies in Development, 43(1), 337-360.spa
dc.relation.referencesPalacios, M. (1999). Parábola del liberalismo, Editorial Norma, Bogotá, pp. 141.spa
dc.relation.referencesPalen, M. (2016). The “Conspiracy” of Free Trade: The Anglo-American Struggle over Empire and Economic Globalization, 1846–1896, New York, Cambridge University Press, pp. Xxxviii, 295.spa
dc.relation.referencesPrebisch, R. (2008 [1980]). Hacia una teoría de la transformación, Revista de la CEPAL No 96, diciembre, pp. 27-71. La primera edición fue publicada en 1980, Revista de la CEPAL No 10, p. 165-216.spa
dc.relation.referencesReinert, E. (1995). “Competitiveness and its predecessors –a 500-year cross-national perspective”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 6, pp 23-42.spa
dc.relation.referencesRoussakis, E. (1969). The Common Market and the Zollverein: Experiences in Integration. Recherches Économiques De Louvain/Louvain Economic Review, 35(3), 201- 208. www.jstor.org/stable/40723212spa
dc.relation.referencesRubin, I. (1979). History of Economic Thought. Inks Liks. (Original publicado en 1929)spa
dc.relation.referencesSachs, Jefrey and Andrew M. Warner (2001). The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review 45 (2001) pp 827-838.spa
dc.relation.referencesSalam, U. (2015). Knowledge as Development’: A Critique of the Knowledge Economy (Thesis Ph. D.) Wolfson College, Oxford, Revised version Trinity 2016, 295 p.spa
dc.relation.referencesSamuelson, P. (1948) International Trade and the Equalisation of Factor Prices. Economic Journal 58 (June):163–84.spa
dc.relation.referencesSamuelson, P. (1948) International Trade and the Equalisation of Factor Prices. Economic Journal 58 (June):163–84.spa
dc.relation.referencesSyrquin, M., & Chenery, H. (1989). Three Decades of Industrialization. The World Bank Economic Review, 3(2), 145-181. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/3989891spa
dc.relation.referencesSzporluk, R. (1988). Communism and Nationalism: Karl Marx versus Friedrich List. Oxford UP.spa
dc.relation.referencesTacchella, A., Cristelli, M., Caldarelli, G. Gabrielli, y Pietronero (2012). A New Metrics for Countries' Fitness and Products' Complexity. Sci Rep 2. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep00723spa
dc.relation.referencesTribe, K. (2002). “Historical Schools of Economics: German and English”, Keele Economics Research Papers, 2002/2, February. pp. twenty.spa
dc.relation.referencesUchitelle, L. (2007, January 30). “A Global Balancing Act”, NYTimes, January 30, p. 1C.spa
dc.relation.referencesUnited Nations. (1949). Post War Price Relations in Trade Between Underdeveloped and Industrialized Countries", document E/CN.1/Sub.3/W.5,23 February 1949.spa
dc.relation.referencesUNTAD. 2016. Trade and Development Report, United Nations, N. York and Geneva, pp. 215.spa
dc.relation.referencesUSTR (2022). Statement from USTR Spokesperson Adam Hodge, December 9. https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/pressreleases/2022/december/statement-ustr-spokesperson-adam-hodgespa
dc.relation.referencesVernengo, M. (2013). Raul Prebisch: A Peripheral Economist at Centre Stage. Development and Change 44(5),1207–1219.spa
dc.relation.referencesVries, P. H. H. (2002). Governing Growth: A Comparative Analysis of the Role of the State in the Rise of the West. Journal of World History 13(1): 67-138.spa
dc.relation.referencesVries, P. (2010), The California School and Beyond: How to Study the Great Divergence?. History Compass, 8: 730-751. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1478-0542.2010.00698.xspa
dc.relation.referencesWitkowska, E. A. (2016) Reconsideration of the Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis, Real-World Economics Review, issue No. 76, pp. 95-108.spa
dc.relation.referencesWorld Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle: economic growth and public policy, WB, Oxford University Press, NY, pp. 389.spa
dc.relation.referencesWorld Bank (2012). China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative High-Income Society (conference Edition), WB, Washington.spa
dc.relation.referencesYoung, A. (1958). Rendimientos Crecientes y Progreso Económico. El Trimestre Económico, 25(99(3)), 483–498. http://www.jstor.org/stable/20855438spa
dc.relation.referencesZuleta, E. (1978). Conferencias sobre historia económica de Colombia, Ediciones Tiempo Crítico, pp. 229.spa
dc.rights.accessrightsinfo:eu-repo/semantics/openAccessspa
dc.rights.licenseAtribución-NoComercial-SinDerivadas 4.0 Internacionalspa
dc.rights.urihttp://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/spa
dc.subject.ddc330 - Economíaspa
dc.subject.lembList, Friedrich, 1789-1846 - Crítica e interpretaciónspa
dc.subject.lembEconomía políticaspa
dc.subject.proposalNacionalismospa
dc.subject.proposalIndustria manufactureraspa
dc.subject.proposalFuerzas productivasspa
dc.subject.proposalCapital mentalspa
dc.subject.proposalEespecificidad históricaspa
dc.subject.proposalInstitucionalismospa
dc.subject.proposalNationalismeng
dc.subject.proposalManufacturing industryeng
dc.subject.proposalProductive forceseng
dc.subject.proposalMental capitaleng
dc.subject.proposalHistorical specificityeng
dc.subject.proposalInstitutionalismeng
dc.titleFriedrich List y la economía política nacionalspa
dc.title.translatedFriedrich List and the national political economyeng
dc.typeTrabajo de grado - Doctoradospa
dc.type.coarhttp://purl.org/coar/resource_type/c_db06spa
dc.type.coarversionhttp://purl.org/coar/version/c_ab4af688f83e57aaspa
dc.type.contentTextspa
dc.type.driverinfo:eu-repo/semantics/doctoralThesisspa
dc.type.redcolhttp://purl.org/redcol/resource_type/TDspa
dc.type.versioninfo:eu-repo/semantics/acceptedVersionspa
dcterms.audience.professionaldevelopmentEstudiantesspa
dcterms.audience.professionaldevelopmentInvestigadoresspa
dcterms.audience.professionaldevelopmentMaestrosspa
oaire.accessrightshttp://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2spa

Archivos

Bloque original

Mostrando 1 - 1 de 1
Cargando...
Miniatura
Nombre:
8354024.2023.pdf
Tamaño:
2.58 MB
Formato:
Adobe Portable Document Format
Descripción:
Tesis de Doctorado en Ciencias Humanas y Sociales

Bloque de licencias

Mostrando 1 - 1 de 1
No hay miniatura disponible
Nombre:
license.txt
Tamaño:
5.74 KB
Formato:
Item-specific license agreed upon to submission
Descripción: